[Dialogue] A good analysis of the situation and the options
KroegerD at aol.com
KroegerD at aol.com
Wed Oct 1 10:58:11 EDT 2008
The Political Nature of the Economic Crisis
September 30, 2008
(http://www.stratfor.com/) By George Friedman
Classical economists like Adam Smith and David Ricardo referred to their
discipline as “political economy.” Smith’s great work, “The Wealth of Nations,”
was written by the man who held the chair in moral philosophy at the
University of Glasgow. This did not seem odd at the time and is not odd now.
Economics is not a freestanding discipline, regardless of how it is regarded today.
It is a discipline that can only be understood when linked to politics, since
the wealth of a nation rests on both these foundations, and it can best be
understood by someone who approaches it from a moral standpoint, since
economics makes significant assumptions about both human nature and proper behavior.
The modern penchant to regard economics as a discrete science parallels the
belief that economics is a distinct sphere of existence — at its best when it
is divorced from political and even moral considerations. Our view has always
been that the economy can only be understood and forecast in the context of
politics, and that the desire to separate the two derives from a moral
teaching that Smith would not embrace. Smith understood that the word “economy”
without the adjective “political” did not describe reality. We need to bear
Smith in mind when we try to understand the current crisis.
Societies have two sorts of financial crises. The first sort is so large it
overwhelms a society’s ability to overcome it, and the society sinks deeper
into dysfunction and poverty. In the second sort, the society has the resources
to manage the situation — albeit at a collective price. Societies that can
manage the crisis have two broad strategies. The first strategy is to allow
the market to solve the problem over time. The second strategy is to have the
state organize the resources of society to speed up the resolution. The market
solution is more efficient over time, producing better outcomes and
disciplining financial decision-making in the long run. But the market solution can
create massive collateral damage, such as high unemployment, on the way to the
superior resolution. The state-organized resolution creates inequities by
not sufficiently punishing poor economic decisions, and creates long-term
inefficiencies that are costly. But it has the virtue of being quicker and
mitigating collateral damage.
Three Views of the Financial Crisis
There is a first group that argues _the current financial crisis_
(http://www.stratfor.com/analysis/20080926_intelligence_guidance_week_sept_28_2008)
already has outstripped available social resources, so that there is no market or
state solution. This group asserts that the imbalances created in the
financial markets are so vast that the market solution must consist of an extended
period of depression. Any attempt by the state to appropriate social
resources to solve the financial imbalance not only will be ineffective, it will
prolong the crisis even further, although perhaps buying some minor alleviation
up front. The thinking goes that the financial crisis has been building for
years and the economy can no longer be protected from it, and that therefore an
extended period of discipline and austerity — beginning with severe economic
dislocations — is inevitable. This is not a majority view, but it is
widespread; it opposes government action on the grounds that the government will
make a terrible situation worse.
A second group argues that the financial crisis has not outstripped the
ability of society — organized by the state — to manage, but that it has
outstripped the market’s ability to manage it. The financial markets have been the
problem, according to this view, and have created a massive liquidity crisis.
The economy — as distinct from the financial markets — is relatively sound,
but if the liquidity crisis is left unsolved, it will begin to affect the
economy as a whole. Since the financial markets are unable to solve the problem
in a time frame that will not dramatically affect the economy, the state must
mobilize resources to impose a solution on the financial markets, introducing
liquidity as the preface to any further solutions. This group believes, like
the first group, that the financial crisis could have profound economic
ramifications. But the second group also believes it is possible to contain the
consequences. This is the view of the Bush administration, _the congressional
leadership_
(http://www.stratfor.com/geopolitical_diary/20080928_geopolitical_diary_congress_plan_u_s_financial_sector) , the Federal Reserve Board and
most economic leaders.
There is a third group that argues that _the state mobilization of resources
to save the financial system_
(http://www.stratfor.com/analysis/global_market_brief_mortgage_bailout_plan_and_u_s_economy) is in fact an attempt to save
financial institutions, including many of those whose imprudence and avarice
caused the current crisis. This group divides in two. The first subgroup
agrees the current financial crisis could have profound economic consequences, but
believes a solution exists that would bring liquidity to the financial
markets without rescuing the culpable. The second subgroup argues that the threat
to the economic system is overblown, and that the financial crisis will
correct itself without major state intervention but with some limited
implementation of new regulations.
The first group thus views the situation as beyond salvation, and certainly
rejects any political solution as incapable of addressing the issues from the
standpoint of magnitude or competence. This group is out of the political
game by its own rules, since for it the situation is beyond the ability of
politics to make a difference — except perhaps to make the situation worse.
The second group represents the establishment consensus, which is that the
markets cannot solve the problem but the federal government can — provided it
acts quickly and decisively enough.
_The third group spoke Sept. 29_
(http://www.stratfor.com/podcast/20080930_congressmen_began_count_cost_their_decision_markets_head_south) , when a
coalition of Democrats and Republicans defeated the establishment proposal. For a
myriad of reasons, some contradictory, this group opposed the bailout. The
reasons ranged from moral outrage at protecting the interests of the perpetrators
of this crisis to distrust of a plan implemented by this presidential
administration, from distrust of the amount of power ceded the Treasury Department
of any administration to a feeling the problem could be managed. It was a
diverse group that focused on one premise — namely, that _delay would not lead
to economic catastrophe_
(http://www.stratfor.com/geopolitical_diary/20080915_geopolitical_diary_measuring_danger) .
>From Economic to Political Problem
The problem ceased to be an economic problem months ago. More precisely, _the
economic problem has transformed into a political problem_
(http://www.stratfor.com/geopolitical_diary/20080929_geopolitical_diary_crises_washington_wall_st
reet) . Ever since _the collapse of Bear Stearns_
(http://www.stratfor.com/analysis/global_market_brief_bear_stearns_bailout_and_calls_oversight) , the
primary actor in the drama has been the federal government and the Federal
Reserve, with its powers increasing as the nature of potential market outcomes
became more and more unsettling. At a certain point, the size of the problem
outstripped the legislated resources of the Treasury and the Fed, so they went
to Congress for more power and money. This time, they were blocked.
It is useful to _reflect on the nature of the crisis_
(http://www.stratfor.com/subprime_geopolitics) . It is a tale that can be as complicated as you wish
to make it, but it is in essence simple and elegant. As interest rates
declined in recent years, investors — particularly conservative ones — sought to
increase their return without giving up safety and liquidity. They wanted
something for nothing, and the market obliged. They were given instruments
_ultimately based on mortgages on private homes_
(http://www.stratfor.com/u_s_subprime_mortgages_and_markets_update) . They therefore had a very real asset base
— a house — and therefore had collateral. The value of homes historically
had risen, and therefore the value of the assets appeared secured. Financial
instruments of increasing complexity eventually were devised, which were
bought by conservative investors. In due course, these instruments were bought by
less conservative investors, who used them as collateral for borrowing money.
They used this money to buy other instruments in a pyramiding scheme that
rested on one premise: the existence of houses whose value remained stable or
grew.
Unfortunately, _housing prices declined_
(http://www.stratfor.com/geopolitical_diary/20080915_geopolitical_diary_measuring_danger) . A period of
uncertainty about the value of the paper based on home mortgages followed. People
claimed to be confused as to what the real value of the paper was. In fact, they
were not so much confused as deceptive. They didn’t want to reveal that the
value of the paper had declined dramatically. At a certain point, the facts
could no longer be hidden, and vast amounts of value evaporated — taking with
them not only the vast pyramids of those who first created the instruments and
then borrowed heavily against them, but also the more conservative investors
trying to put their money in a secure space while squeezing out a few extra
points of interest. The decline in housing prices triggered massive losses of
money in the financial markets, as well as reluctance to lend based on
uncertainty of values. The result was a liquidity crisis, which simply meant that a
lot of people had gone broke and that those who still had money weren’t
lending it — certainly not to financial institutions.
The S&L Precedent
Such financial meltdowns based on shifts in real estate prices are not new.
In the 1970s, regulations on savings and loans (S&Ls) had changed.
Previously, S&Ls had been limited to lending in the consumer market, primarily in
mortgages for homes. But the regulations shifted, and they became allowed to
invest more broadly. The assets of these small banks, of which there were
thousands, were attractive in that they were a pool of cash available for investment.
The S&Ls subsequently went into commercial real estate, sometimes with their
old management, sometimes with new management who had bought them, as their
depositors no longer held them.
The infusion of money from the S&Ls drove up the price of commercial real
estate, which the institutions regarded as stable and conservative investments,
not unlike private homes. They did not take into account that their presence
in the market was driving up the price of commercial real estate i
rrationally, however, or that commercial real estate prices fluctuate dramatically. As
commercial real estate values started to fall, the assets of the S&Ls
contracted until most failed. An entire sector of the financial system simply
imploded, crushing shareholders and threatening a massive liquidity crisis. By the
late 1980s, the entire sector had melted down, and in 1989 the federal
government intervened.
The federal government intervened in that crisis as it had in several crises
large and small since 1929. Using the resources at its disposal, the federal
government took over failed S&Ls and their real estate investments, creating
the Resolution Trust Corp. (RTC). The amount of assets acquired was about
$394 billion dollars in 1989 — or 6.7 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) —
making it larger than the $700 billion dollars — or 5 percent of GDP —
being discussed now. Rather than flooding the markets with foreclosed commercial
property, creating havoc in the market and further destroying assets, the RTC
held the commercial properties off the market, maintaining their price
artificially. They then sold off the foreclosed properties in a multiyear
sequence that recovered much of what had been spent acquiring the properties. More
important, it prevented the decline in commercial real estate from
accelerating and creating liquidity crises throughout the entire economy.
Many of those involved in S&Ls were ruined. Others managed to use the RTC
system to recover real estate and to profit. Still others came in from the
outside and used the RTC system to build fortunes. The RTC is not something to
use as moral lesson for your children. But the RTC managed to prevent the
transformation of a financial crisis into an economic meltdown. It disrupted
market operations by introducing large amounts of federal money to bring liquidity
to the system, then used the ability of the federal government — not shared
by individuals — to hold on to properties. The disruption of the market’s
normal operations was designed to avoid a market outcome. By holding on to the
assets, the federal government was able to create an artificial market in real
estate, one in which supply was constrained by the government to manage the
value of commercial real estate. It did not work perfectly — far from it. But
it managed to avoid the most feared outcome, which was a depression.
There have been many other federal interventions in the markets, such as the
bailout of Chrysler in the 1970s or the intervention into failed Third World
bonds in the 1980s. _Political interventions in the American (or global)
marketplace_
(http://www.stratfor.com/analysis/20080919_u_s_market_intervention_far_unprecedented_move) are hardly novel. They are used to control the
consequences of bad decisions in the marketplace. Though they introduce
inefficiencies and frequently reward foolish decisions, they achieve a single end:
limiting the economic consequences of these decisions on the economy as a whole.
Good idea or not, these interventions are institutionalized in American
economic life and culture. The ability of Americans to be shocked at the thought of
bailouts is interesting, since they are not all that rare, as judged
historically.
The RTC showed the ability of federal resources — using taxpayer dollars —
_to control financial processes_
(http://www.stratfor.com/analysis/global_market_brief_takeover_twins) . In the end, the S&L story was simply one of bad
decisions resulting in a shortage of dollars. On top of a vast economy, the U.S.
government can mobilize large amounts of dollars as needed. It therefore can
redefine the market for money. It did so in 1989 during the S&L crisis, and
there was a general acceptance it would do so again Sept. 29.
The RTC Model and the Road Ahead
As discussed above, the first group argues the current crisis is so large
that it is beyond the federal government’s ability to redefine. More precisely,
it would argue that the attempt at intervention would unleash other
consequences — such as _weakening dollars_
(http://www.stratfor.com/weekly/china_and_arabian_peninsula_market_stabilizers) and inflation — meaning the cure would
be worse than the disease. That may be the case this time, but it is difficult
to see why the consequences of this bailout would be profoundly different
from the RTC bailout — namely, a normal recession that would probably happen
anyway.
The debate between the political leadership and those opposing its plan is
more interesting. The fundamental difference between the RTC and the current
bailout was institutional. Congress created a semi-independent agency operating
under guidelines to administer the S&L bailout. The proposal that was
defeated Sept. 29 would have given the secretary of the Treasury extraordinary
personal powers to dispense the money. Some also argued that the return on the
federal investment was unclear, whereas in the RTC case it was fairly clear. In
the end, all of this turned on the question of urgency. The establishment
group argued that time was running out and the financial crisis was about to
morph into an economic crisis. Those voting against the proposal argued there
was enough time to have a more defined solution.
There was obviously a more direct political dimension to all this. Elections
are just more than a month a way, and the seat of every U.S. representative
is in contest. The public is deeply distrustful of the establishment, and
particularly of the idea that the people who caused the crisis might benefit
from the bailout. The congressional opponents of the plan needed to demonstrate
sensitivity to public opinion. Having done so, if they force a redefinition of
the bailout plan, an additional 13 votes can likely be found to pass the
measure.
But the key issue is this: Are the resources of the United States sufficient
to redefine financial markets in such a way as to manage the outcome of this
crisis, or has the crisis become so large that even the resources of a $14
trillion economy mobilized by the state can’t do the job? If the latter is
true, then all other discussions are irrelevant. Events will take their course,
and nothing can be done. But if that is not true, that means that politics
defines the crisis, as it has other crisis. In that case, the federal government
can marshal the resources needed to redefine the markets and the key
decision-makers are not on Wall Street, but in Washington. Thus, when the chips are
down, the state trumps the markets.
All of this may not be desirable, efficient or wise, but as an empirical
fact, it is the way American society works and has worked for a long time. We
are seeing a case study in it — including the possibility the state will refuse
to act, creating an interesting and profound situation. This would allow the
market alone to define the outcome of the crisis. This has not been allowed
in extreme crises in 75 years, and we suspect this tradition of intervention
will not be broken now. The federal government will act in due course, and an
institutional resolution taking power from the Treasury and placing it in
_the equivalent of the RTC_
(http://www.stratfor.com/analysis/20080919_global_market_brief_biggest_piece_plan) will emerge. The question is how much time
remains before massive damage is done to the economy.
_Tell Stratfor What You Think_ (http://www.stratfor.com/cont
act?type=responses&subject=RE:+The+Political+Nature+of+the+Economic+Crisis)
This report may be forwarded or republished on your website with attribution
to _www.stratfor.com_ (http://www.stratfor.com/)
**************Looking for simple solutions to your real-life financial
challenges? Check out WalletPop for the latest news and information, tips and
calculators. (http://www.walletpop.com/?NCID=emlcntuswall00000001)
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://wedgeblade.net/pipermail/dialogue_wedgeblade.net/attachments/20081001/5ad2bf28/attachment-0001.html>
More information about the Dialogue
mailing list