Global Research Assembly
Chicago
July 1977S
I thought I would start out by telling
you where I come from. With a group of people like you, where
we come from isn't something we talk about at coffee time that
doesn't matter. We are all here because we are dissatisfied with
something; we are searching for something. I first became involved
with what is commonly and much too narrowly described as economic
development 20 years ago. I went overseas in 1960, first to West
Pakistan and then to East Pakistan, now Bangladesh.
The first two years when I was in the
western side of the country I immediately started traveling around
the countryside because I had what many people told me was a naive
idea in my head Because the people in West Pakistan live in villages,
I assumed that development was mostly about villages. As I rambled
around, I didn't find much happening.
Some physical things were being done.
Governments love to build things, and we all know that. There
were new schools, community halls and wells, but there was no
spirit of adventure and no fun, no sense of involvement. The things
I took for granted that might be happening in villages, I just
did not find.
This was at a time when Pakistan was
being hailed as a model of a successful developing country. It
was 18 months after Ayub Khan had taken control of the government
and brought in a group of people from Harvard who put together
a model fiveyear plan in a manner in which economists do
this. On the one hand, I was constantly being told that this country
was a model of how to do economic development and on the other
hand, I didn't see anything.
In 1962, I went to East Pakistan. There,
I conducted three experimental programs, experimental simply because
they were different. At that time I had resigned from the orthodox
or what we sometimes call the trickledown approach to development,
partly because of my experience with the three experimental programs
in Bangladesh. Ever since then I have been part of an increasing
number of people who have been hunting for a better, more human,
more decentralized approach to economic development.
I came home for a short time in 1964.
I started to read and talk to people, share experiences and reached
the point in the midsixties when I decided to speak out
about my own experiences of what I thought I had learned. I very
quickly got caught up in a lot of technical arguments with Ph.D's
over such things as whether small farms could be efficient and
whether poor people can save money and so on. For about ten years
now I have sensed that I spend a fair amount of my life arguing
with the socalled experts and as nicely as I can, trying
to tell them that they are wrong.
As the years have passed I have decided
the fundamental issues of development are really more serious,
much more basic than the technical issues the professionals and
Ph.D's argue about. I am writing a book, trying to summarize what
seems to be the most critical basic issue in the debate about
development. I will read from one of the chapters:
"In the modernizing world of GNP,
villagers and slum dwellers lack the knowledge and experience
that are needed to resolve technical problems. We all know this.
National governments and foreign aid agencies can follow one of
two courses in dealing with these people.
First, they can assume that People are
the Problem. In this approach, decisions are made almost entirely
by experts and officials who are highly educated and hopefully
experienced. Innovation and spontaneity are controlled from the
national capital from the top down. Planning is considered to
be a specialized function carried on by a handful who are trained
for the purpose, and action supposedly begins with the analyses
and recommendations of planners and other experts. The role of
village and slum dwellers is simply to accept and apply the recommendations
that are handed down to them even though they have not been involved
in identifying the problem and may not know how to use the technology
which is supposed to be used to solve it.
For villagers and slum dwellers, there
is no pride in a kind of abject obedience, and this is their relationship
to governments, officials, experts and people from foreign aid
agencies. If you assume that people are the problem, then the
professionals, experts and officials are the solution."
A quotation from the Russian novelist
Leo Tolstoy aptly summarizes the relationship between government
and people in this 'PeoplearetheProblem' approach.
"I sit on a man's back choking him and making him carrying
me and yet assure myself and others that I am sorry for him and
wish to lighten his load by all possible means except by getting
off his back." Practically all the developing countries are
following this 'PeoplearetheProblem' approach.
So also are the foreign aid agencies and regretfully, the one
that employs me.
The second course which governments and
foreign aid agencies can follow and which ICA is following is
to assume that People are the Solution. If villagers and urban
slum dwellers lack knowledge and experience, then government should
help them acquire the former through the latter. The model of
learning in this approach is aptly summarized in a wellknown
couplet from Confucius which goes like this: "I hear and
I forget. I see and I remember. I do and I understand." The
approach of the ICA is the "I do and I understand."
Most governments and foreign aid agencies have been following
the "I hear and I see" approaches and people do not
get involved.
In the second course, planning is a form
of participation, a way of involving large numbers of people in
decisionmaking. Development is not a handful of projects
planned by the national governments a highway here
and a factory there. Rather, development becomes a part of the
routine activities of everyday life millions of individual
deeds by millions of individual people. Deeds in which people
can feel the pride of achievement. The role of experts and administrators
is to advise, help, teach and listen but not to try to give other
people the answers to their problems.
A couple of years ago I would have said
that is the problem overseas. In the past several years I have
spent some time working with groups in the Washington area concerned
with domestic problems, and I have come to realize that many of
the questions that I have been fretting about for so many years
in the socalled underdeveloped countries are questions which
are valid here at home. I have concluded now that participation,
or rather, the lack of it, is the most important political problem
of our time and that this is true in the rich democracies, in
the rich communist countries and in the underdeveloped nations
as well.
I'd like to give you a quick history
of the debate about development in the hope that it will help
put your experience and your impressions about the underdeveloped
countries into some kind of perspective. Concerning this debate
about development, I want to add that this is relevant here at
home as well.
Back in the early fifties when foreign
aid began, there quickly grew up the orthodox or trickledown
approach to development and it consisted of two things. First
of all, development was defined as a problem in economics, and
the notion was that if investment increased and GNP rose, all
kinds of wonderful things would happen. People would have jobs;
they would have food; they would be able to buy medical services;
government would gain more taxes; they would be able to build
schools and so on.
This emphasis on investment was combined
with a particular type of rural development known as Community
Development. Now, this is with a capital 'C' and a capital 'D'
and it refers to a particular set of ideas that comes from social
welfare theory. It does not refer to the development of community
in a general sense. This original approach to rural development
was strictly done in a topdown manner. The whole program
is based on the notion that villagers are lazy and shiftless
all the things you've heard education people say if you've worked
overseas. Therefore, government would have to make their decisions
for them.
The emphasis on teaching people how to
collect data, think about their own problems, talk about alternative
solutions, which is the very heart of the ICA process did not
exist in the original approach to rural development this
thing I called Community Development. It began in the early fifties
and went on for about 15 years. For a decade and a half, this
was the common rural development program that you found all over
the world, first in Asia, then in Africa and Latin America, but
eventually it became common in all three continents.
Let me digress for just a moment. If
you would accept the notion that the ultimate test of any rural
program is loyalty, Community Development flunked the ultimate
test in South Viet Nam. The program that the American government
supported there in its attempts to win the hearts of the people
in South Viet Nam was based on Community Development theory
and we all know it failed.
Trickledown consists of two things
this emphasis on increasing GNP and Community Development.
On the GNP side it was assumed that the fastest way to do this
was to copy the big farm, big factory, big technologytype
production systems we have in the United States and other Western
countries. Trickledown is now dead, fortunately.
Historians might describe the 1970is
as a period of transition in development theory. We now know that
the Western bigfarm, bigfactory approach does not
make sense in the poor countries because they are overwhelmingly
a world of smallness. Eighty per cent of the farms in the developing
world are 12 acres or less and in some countries, the crowded
Asian countries, the average farm may be as little as two or three
acres. Either we learn how to make these tiny farms more productive
or some of these countries aren't going to succeed in development.
Obviously, an American size tractor doesn't fit a twoacre
farm and even if it did, people with an income of $300 to $400
per year couldn't afford to buy it. Most business and industrial
enterprises are equally small. From the point of view of an American
going to a developing country, it is a little bit like Gulliver
in the land of Lilliput. We have learned this now.
During the sixties, economists began
to study this problem of smallness and also the question of whether
the poor could save. We have discovered that indeed, they can
save, and out of this work has grown a subject called Small Producer
Economics. It simply turns upside down all the economic premises
we started with in the early 1950's. I want to mention the three
key premises. Small farms are more efficient than large farms,
so it makes sense for ICA to be doing the work with small farms
that it is doing. In most categories of industry the same thing
is true. Concerning savings, we have now learned that given the
right set of circumstances, the poor, even if their incomes are
just a couple of hundred dollars a year, can learn to save and
in the long run, pay the cost of their own improvement. The whole
economics of development theory has changed.
There is another aspect of the new ideas
on development with which I am sure you are all familiar, Appropriate
Technology. I'm sure you've all heard of a book called "Small
is Beautiful," written by Schumacher. He called it Intermediate
Technology. The name has changed since then. I will try to illustrate
what a difference appropriate technology could make in an economy.
And to use a type of technology that is totally different from
what we have here in the States, I'd like to ask you to use your
imaginations for a couple of minutes along these lines.
Let's suppose that the U.S. were as densely
populated as Taiwan which is one of the most successful of all
the developing countries in the Third World. How many people would
there be in the United States? The answer is almost three and
a half billion or about 801 of all the people in the world today
would live in this country. Now, if there were that many Americans,
would it be possible to have a fully employed economy? Somewhat
surprisingly, the answer Is yes. Of that large number of people,
the labor force would be one and a half billion, and of that one
and a half billion the number of farmers would be a little over
four hundred million roughly double the total population
of the U.S. today. The average size farm would be only 2.2. acres.
Nevertheless, we would have a highly productive farming system
with farm incomes increasing. And then, If you looked at the industrial
and service sectors, we would have a fully employed economy even
with that large number of Americans.
Now, that says one thing we can talk
about quickly and that is obviously, the technology used in Taiwan
is radically different from what is used in the U.S. There Is
only one characteristic about it that I want to mention because
it Is the opposite of what we have all been brought up to believe.
We tend to think that technology Is something
which not only makes people more productive but that it reduces
the number of people needed to do a job. Technical machines tend
to be labor replacing. In Taiwan, technology is job creating.
One of the tasks which Americans have to engage in if we are going
to be helpful overseas is to think of how we can use tools and
equipment to make people more productive, but without replacing
them it is possible.
I'd like to take these notions and comment
on one of the major unsolved problems of development. This will
Illustrate how a few countries which have followed a smallisbeautiful
participatory approach to development are doing so much better
than most countries which are really dual economics.
I mentioned that Taiwan is perhaps the
most successful of the developing countries. Taiwan's system of
local organizations has enabled the poor in that country to become
members of a modern production system so that productivity and
income are both rising. Length of life is about the same as in
the U.S., but their infant mortality is a little lower than here,
for the infant mortality rate among our minorities Is quite high.
Quite possibly they have a better diet. They now have enough money
to get the foods they need but they don't have enough to purchase
the junk food that we eat.
The world food problem Is essentially
a shortage of just one thing, the good grain or carbohydrate that
people eat wherever they happen to live. The most common grains
are rice, wheat and corn. The question Is whether villagers and
slum dwellers have enough of that one thing so that they are not
hungry. The world food problem Is not a problem of nutrition;
it Is purely a question of whether a person's stomach Is full
or not. For this reason, the statistics on food grain productivity
are a quick indicator of how well a country is doing In feeding
Its own people.
I'd like to point out just a couple of
statistics which will be very simple. First of all, in the rich
countries in general, the output per acre of the basic food grains
runs from three thousand pounds up to 4500. Let's just say 3000
and over. In the U.S., it's about 3100. In Taiwan it's about 3800
and it is slightly more than twice as high as it was when the
Chinese revolution ended. It is the highest of any of the countries
in the developing world. We've all heard about something called
the Green Revolution which started in Mexico, and how marvelous
it is supposed to be.
In Mexico, this same statistic is about
1,350 pounds per acre and that's all. Now Mexico is cited by many
people as the world's classic example of a dual economy and a
lot of people make comparisons between Taiwan and Mexico partly
because both have a history of development that is about 50 years
old. Mexico's farming community is divided between a rather small
number of large farms with American style mechanization similar
to the farming systems of Texas, Arizona, and New Mexico.
If you cross the border you will find
the same style of division in Mexico. For the onesixth of
Mexico's farmers who are involved in this system, things are very
good. Productivity is going up and their incomes are going up.
All of the things that are supposed to happen in agriculture are
happening, for onesixth of Mexico's farmers. But the other
fivesixths, the little farmers, have been mostly left out;
and their productivity today is about as low as it was in 1950,
when development began. If you know the situation, where there
is a small number of fairly efficient large producers and a very
large number of low productivity small producers, the national
average is going to be quite low.
That's the reason why this food grain
statistic, the 1350 pounds for Mexico, is so much lower than in
Taiwan. In Taiwan, all the farmers are involved; in Mexico, just
some. In relation to the 1350 pounds, in most of the developing
countries, food grain productivity is that, or lower. Yet, the
technical potential for growing food in most of the countries
should make it possible for most of them to reach the 3000 pounds
per acre or more, that you find in the rich countries. I believe
that the problem has nothing to do with technology. The question
is whether the poor are going to be involved, whether they're
going to have a chance to improve their own lot in life, and also
improve the general situation of their country.
At this point I would like to make a
comment about Bangladesh and Taiwan. Bangladesh is often cited
as the 'basket case', where nothing can be done. For people who
live in a sparsely populated country, this image seems reasonable.
Bangladesh is the size of Arkansas and it already has 85 million
people. You look at Arkansas and you think about 85 million people
and you scratch your head and say, "Heavens!" The birth
rate is very high and by the year 2000, Bangladesh could have
170 million people. Well then, you not only scratch your head,
you tear your hair out, and say, "What can you do?"
Well, if Bangladesh were as densely populated as Taiwan, Bangladesh
would have 170 million people, today. More to the point, she would
almost, but not quite, feed herself.
Taiwan could feed herself if it were
necessary. If this were an academic classroom, there would be
a few qualifications on that point, which we can skip for here.
The point is that there are a small number of countries in the
world which have created what is known in the professional community
as Small Farm Labor Intensive Agricultural Systems. In spite of
their extraordinarily dense population, they have achieved very
high agricultural productivity and can more or less feed themselves.
They are Japan, Taiwan, South Korea, Egypt to a lesser extent,
and also China.
It is quite true to say that the central
problem of rural development Is the reconstruction of a village.
To rearrange human relationships so that the dependency of the
poor on a handful of landlords, regents, or merchants, whomever
it is; is broken, so that the great mass of the ordinary people
of the villages have a chance to do things for themselves for
the first time. That is an incredibly tough problem!
This is one which you have learned how to solve, and not very
many people in the world have solved it.
In addition, the question of 'linkages'
should be mentioned. Barbara Ward defines world development as,
"the process of creating linkages between farm village and
market town." The first question is, Why do these linkages
need to be created? Well, a lot of things that need to be done
in a market economy are too big to be done at the village level
with any kind of low unit cost. If you sum up the total amount
of land which is owned by a village community in India, the total
amount of fertilizer the farmers use, the amount of credit they
need, the amount of produce which they have to market, by and
large, the quantities are too small to handle these business transactions
at a low unit cost. This is what the economists call the 'Economy's
Scale Argument'. That's a problem all developing countries face,
and it's solved simply by grouping villages together into what
we would call a township or a county.
One of the things that needs to be done
is to handle some of the activities on a village cluster basis
with the headquarters of an organization such as the cooperative
in the market town. Or certain types of investments such as warehouses
or a few simple industries, such as food grain mills, could be
located in the market town because they cannot be put in every
village. This must be done, or just organizing individual villages
won't accomplish much.
Another major problem has to do with
the relationship between a village organizational program and
governments. One of the things that badly needs to be done in
India is to decentralize the government administration, both the
national government and the state government. The point at which
the government needs to provide services of many kinds to the
people is what Americans would call a county. If you look around
the world on this point and try to answer a question that most
of us wouldn't think of asking, "Where does the central government
go, if it really wants to work with the people?" The answer
is, almost everywhere, regardless of political system, is the
county.
Now, up until recently, nobody paid any
attention to local government as a development body. In India,
now, there are all kinds of things that the local government can
do that will help villages. The local government can provide the
whole range of agricultural extension research, credit, medical
services, education, and so on. These are services which governments
need to provide at the lowest level of the state government, where
people who are trained in medicine, in health, in agricultural
extension, whatever it may be. The place where they should be
grouped together is at what we will call the county level.
Then the problem is, how do you create
linkages between that group of people and the village communities.
Representatives of the villages, people that are called village
extension agents could become the contact point between the agricultural
extension agent and the village. When it came time to introduce
some new innovation in agriculture - new crop or fertilizer, the
job of the extension agent is to work with the one or two individuals
who are the representatives of the village, and then it is those
people who introduce it to their fellow villagers. Innovation
does not come from without, but it can come from within the village
if it's brought into the village by villagers, themselves.
There are a few countries where this
relationship between the local government, or call it the lowest
level field office of the national government, and village organizations
has been worked out in great detail, and very successfully. The
commune of China represents this kind of relationship. The Township
in Taiwan represents the same kind of relationship. The combination
of the local government, the farmers' association, the irrigation
association, in Taiwan, represent the organizations of the villagers
and a whole variety of things are done by the local government.
A whole variety of services provided by the local government actually
come from the central government of Taiwan.
There is ample experience to draw on
to try and solve this problem. Linking villages to a broader community,
the state and eventually the net tonal economy, is important to
make people know that they are a part of something much bigger
than just the little village in which they live. Of course it's
the nature of modern society, a modern economy, that this has
been done in the so-called rich countries.
Now, I would like to conclude by making
a few comments about the United States. Back in 1972 and 1973,
I began to work on some domestic problems, with domestic groups,
and to my surprise, discovered that there were many similarities
between the things I'd been thinking about overseas and things
which people were beginning to do here at home. The same kinds
of questions that I had been arguing about with experts with respect
to the poor countries are now being raised in the United States.
For example, "Is big really beautiful?"
There's been some research done on efficiency
and the size of firms in the United States. What we are beginning
to discover is that, even though an industry can be too small
to be efficient, it can also be too large. So 'big' may not always
be beautiful, as we've been led to believe. We're also coming
to realize that technology is not nearly as inflexible as we were
brought up to believe. I was taught that technology was a certain
something and you had to use it a certain way or not use it at
all. It was big and kept getting bigger and if we wanted to have
it, we had to accept it that way. We are now learning that technology
is much more flexible than we'd been taught. A while ago, I asked
an industrial engineer what he thought about the possibilities
of designing things small without any loss of efficiency. He said,
"Sure, why not? But you know, nobody has ever asked me to
do that." And many people in the United States are now starting
to ask that kind of question.
Let me now make one comment on why I
talk so much about economists and technical people and professional
people. We live in a society that's been highly materialistic
and when development and foreign aid began, we took our type of
materialism overseas. The key people in this materialistic society
happen to be economists, as we all know, and one of the things
that dawned on some of us in the sixties was that unless we could
beat economists on their own terms we would never win the case
for participation of the poor in development. So in effect we
said, "We are going to play your game by your rules. On your
field, we're the visiting team and we're going to beat you."
And we have. We have now demonstrated that small farms can be
efficient.
I think these same questions are going
to be raised in the United States. We must be able to demonstrate
that we can have smaller production units, and smaller markets,
in the U.S. and still have a high standard of living. We have
to change the conventional wisdom of the establishment, and I'm
quite optimistic that within the next five or ten years we'll
be able to do just this. And so I now conclude by saying that
just as we have recognized the need to reconsider development
overseas, and in fact have done it, I think it's now fit and proper
that we should reconsider development here at home. Let's turn
now to questions and answers.
HOW CAN SMALL FARMS BE EXTREMELY PRODUCTIVE?
WHAT ARE THEY DOING IN TAIWAN?
What they are doing, in a sense, Ts the
same thing that American farmers do. They have good seeds. They
have access to fertilizer, and they can borrow money. They do
all this through their coop, and they have access to the
market so that when the time comes to sell it, they can. The point
about Taiwan is that institutions have been used to bring the
poor into the modern economy, and the government has used its
power when necessary to make sure that the poor would get a certain
minimum set of benefits. The twoacre farmer gets his twoacre
share of fertilizer just as the 72 acre farmer. That's the maximum
farm size in Taiwan.
There is a quotation from Barbara Ward
that summarizes the problem implicit in your question.) Barbara
Ward is a well known British economist. I sometimes describe her
as the 'Queen of Development'. "A market system wholly uncorrected
by institutions of justice, sharing, and solidarity makes the
strong stronger and the weak weaker. Markets as useful tools in
a functioning social order have a positive and decentralizing
role to play. Markets, as master of society, enrich the rich and
pauperize the poor."
In most countries the larger farmers,
for example, as individuals can get a loan. They can contact the
government extension agent, and they can sell their stuff at the
market. Small farmers can not do these things individually. The
reason for the emphasis on what Barbara Ward describes as 'institutions
of justice, sharing, and solidarity' is that it is only through
institutions that the poor gain access. It is in that sense that
Taiwan is a highly participatory country. The institutions, such
as the coop, the irrigation association, and the local government,
were set up so that the poor would have access to credit, the
market, and technology. Most countries haven't treated development
that way.
They have followed the trickledown
approach and simply assumed that if the Gross National Product
were going up high enough, everybody would benefit. Then Taiwan
has also begun land reform.
Most countries haven't taken land reform
seriously. In India, for example, about onehalf of the number
of farmers or less that even if they were good farmers,
they could not make much living out of just one acre. The only
way that enough jobs can be created to employ the huge mass of
people in India is through some modest amount of land reform.
This could happen as it did in Japan, Taiwan, South Korea, and
Egypt. These are the four major successful land reform programs
since World War Two. It is absolutely not true to say that the
problem in India is too many people on too little land. India
has about five times as much cultivatable land per person as Taiwan.
It also has more cultivatable land per person than most of the
countries in Western Europe, more than Egypt, and twice as much
as China. It's a question of how government organizes the system
and whether it skews the benefits toward the rich and whether
everybody gets a certain minimum share.
WHAT YOU SAID ABOUT THE COUNTY LEVEL
IS INTERESTING BECAUSE A LOT OF OUR WORK THIS YEAR HAS BEEN ORIENTED
TOWARD THE COUNTY LEVEL. COULD YOU SAY A LITTLE MORE ABOUT THAT?
Some of you may have heard of a very
famous world development project that existed in the sixties in
what is now called Bangladesh. I consider the man who started
it to be the number one authority in the world development. Back
in the fifties when he was beginning to reconsider development
himself, one of the questions he asked himself was, "If a
central government really wants to work with its people, where
does it go?" He never met a single Westerner or any other
human being who could answer it. In those days, there were people
in the AID mission in Pakistan who knew the history of economic
development in Western countries, and he would ask them this question
and they would just look at him. He found the answer in the history
books. He discovered that almost universally the level at which
the government and the people meet is the county.
The one exception is that in some of
the very crowded countries of East Asia, counties are cut up into
four or five pieces what we call a township. Japan, China,
and Taiwan are the three. The commune in China is more like what
we would call a township than a county, and it is really quite
small. The average number of people in a commune, we think, is
about twelve to fifteen thousand people. That's not very big.
We need to go back into our own history.
Some of our forebearers, particularly Thomas Jefferson, came up
with answers which we seem to have forgotten. As Americans, what
we have to do is look at our own past to find answers for today's
problems. We've all heard in history books of the Northwest Ordinance
of 1787. It is one of two important statutes passed in the days
of the Articles of Confederation. We've been told that this was
the law that somehow guarded the opening up of the West. If that
law was reexamined in terms of what is now known as regional
planning for rural development, we find that Thomas Jefferson
was a first class rural development strategist. He outlined the
expansion of the West by creating a certain area we call the county
seat.
It can also be called the market town
in the middle of an area with certain economic, social, educational,
and health institutions needed by a rural population. He was creating
linkages between farm and village and market town 200 years before
Barbara Ward ever wrote down the phrase, 'linkages'. Assuming
you have an outline of the problems of a local community and some
outside help including some from the government, that's what you
do at the county level. And it depends on the local situation
to ask for the kinds of services the government can provide.
YOU HAVE QUOTED SOME VERY OPTIMISTIC
PRODUCTION FIGURES OBTAINED WITH OILBASED FERTILIZERS. WHAT WOULD
BE YOUR PRODUCTION FIGURE BASED ON NON OILBASED FERTILIZERS?
Nobody really knows the answer to that
yet. The high productivity systems are based on oilbased
fertilizer, and one of the technical problems of the future is
to figure out a new approach or a different type of scientific
farming that uses some fertilizer but not the vast quantities
we are using now.
Some research is being done on so called
organic farming. Basically we don't know the answer to your question.
The universities and the agricultural research stations, not only
in the U.S. but in other places, ought to be putting far more
of their research budgets into alternative farming systems. We've
got to find a different approach to high productivity farming.
COULD YOU GIVE US AN EXAMPLE OF SMALL
INDUSTRIES WHICH ARE EFFICIENT?
There is not a great deal to be said
about it except that there appears to be a wide variety of industries
in which it's possible to design smaller and still be efficient.
What you do in any one case depends on the product, the crop,
the market, and other things. The people who now hire industrial
designers in the U.S. are primarily big business and big government.
We need to change that so that more communityoriented people
are in the business of hiring industrial designers. Hopefully,
these people will be able to come up with minifactories
for many products. There are many factories in a few production
processes. There's a minisugar refinery that was designed
by an Indian that is about 10% the size of our sugar refinery.
The British have built a miniplant, and there's a mintsoap
plant in Ghana. These minifactories designed thus far suggest
that there could be hundreds of thousands of possibilities.
WHEN YOU USE THE WORD 'BIG', DO YOU ONLY
MEAN EFFICIENCY?
Bigness is not a matter of efficiency
but of economic power. In the U.S. today there are small groups
all over, including people in this room, who are trying to figure
out how to provide capital for smaller business. People are beginning
to find answers to this problem. As people find answers, we'll
begin to find what alternative solution in the U.S. that is possible,
and that's when it will start to happen.
WHAT WILL BE THE RESULTS OF THE RECENT
SHAKEUP IN THE 'SMALL BUSINESS LOAN'S BUREAU'?
There'll be a lot of fuss and furor about
it, and they might tighten up the regulations a little. If they
do, it will make it harder for the smallest of the small to get
a loan than it is now.
YOU TALKED ABOUT THE FARMCOMMUNITY
LINKAGE IN TAIWAN, AND I THINK YOU WERE REFERRING TO THE COOPERATIVES.
IS THE PRINCIPLE OF COOPERATIVES OVER THERE DIFFERENT THAN THE
PRINCIPLE OF COOPERATIVES HERE IN THE UNITED STATES?
The general principle is the same, but
I do not think the history of cooperatives in the U.S. as being
very helpful as a guide to what ought to be done in developing
countries. I think what is known as the Japanese multipurpose
cooperative or the Danish multipurpose cooperative is a
much better model of what might be useful in the countries than
what we have in the United States.
WHAT'S THE RELATIONSHIP AND ROLE OF THE
SMALL FARM COOPERATIVE TO THE COMMUNITY?
It's a twotiered model and its
pattern can be copied. The base unit of a Taiwanese cooperative
or one in Japan or in the Chinese rural commune
is called by the Taiwanese a small agricultural unit. It
is the extended family in the village. If the village is small,
the chances are it's just one extended family, and that whole
family is the small agricultural unit. In larger villages, there
are probably a couple of extended families, so there may be several
small agricultural units. This is the traditional social organization.
On the one hand you have to maintain the cohesion of it, and on
the other hand, you have to change it so that the people at the
bottom get a better break in the future than they have had in
the past. That unit is then linked to the township the
name in Taiwan is the Farmers' Association. The chairman and the
deputy chairman of the small agricultural unit belong to what
is called the General Assembly of the Township Cooperative. The
General Assembly picks out seven people who are Executive Committee
for one year what we would call the Board of Directors.
So you have a modern business organizational
structure linked into a traditional social structure. To make
that combination work is really the trick of development, because
you must maintain the integrity of the original village community,
and yet you must modernize it and change it without destroying
it. These East Asian countries have used this device of the village
cluster in putting the formal organization at the cluster level,
or the county level, combining that with the traditional village
community. That combination is the common pattern where villages
are involved.
THERE SEEMS TO BE A STRONG TRADITION
AGAINST SMALL FARMS IN THIS COUNTRY. WHAT MAJOR FACTORS CONTRIBUTE
TO THAT?
There has been this not Ton in the United
States that small farms were inefficient and that the small farmers
are really a labor force for factories. The not Ton that the number
of farmers in a country should decline seems almost like a natural
law of hi story in the Western world, because that's what happened
everywhere. We didn't have to keep people on the farm because
we never had a population explosion.
So, I think the whole bias of government
policy of American industry has been against the small farmer,
from times past, with one exception the Farm Security Administration
during the 1930's. But, that didn't last very long and it was
regarded, I think by the government and the business and professional
community, as a kind of aberration that was necessary at the time
of the depression a welfare program, but not an agricultural
system. It has not been believed that small farms, American style,
ten, twenty, maybe fifty acres, might be efficient and not only
provide a decent way of life but a people with a decent income.
In the U.S. now, you find people who
are trying to figure out whether it is possible to have an American
version of a small farm system. Some work is being done on pumping
patterns and mechanization. Obviously, you have to have a very
different style of mechanization in the States if we're going
to have small farmers that can be efficient. I'm optimistic about
the outcome, myself.
I don't think it's that difficult to
design gadgets; it's getting them into use that's the tougher
problem. There are people like Robert Rodale who publishes "Organic
Gardening and Farming". He has a research section up in Pennsylvania
and a very good agricultural engineer; they have gone into the
business of designing tools and equipment for horticulture. If
we have somebody like him to go to work on equipment for 2550
acre farms, why not as soon as possible? There are other people
in the country who are also interested in small farms. A number
of companies and a few people in the university community are
beginning to depart from the conventional wisdom and are beginning
to worry about small farms, but they're very few in number.
DON'T WE NEED GOOD MODELS OF AGRICENTERS,
SELFSUFFICIENT RURAL COMMUNITIES, IN THE UNITED STATES OR
MODELS OF ATTEMPTS TO ORGANIZE COMMUNITIES ON THE CLUSTER PATTERN
IN THE UNITED STATES?
Historically, I would say our whole country
was like that. Now, I don't think there is such a thing as a model.
I don't think it's possible for someone to say, "Go to Vermont
or California, and you'll find it." What you will find in
Vermont and California and some other places are people who are
trying to figure out an alternative pattern. And, they can tell
you what they're trying to do and all the problems involved in
it. They haven't done it yet, because it's too new.
WHO ARE THE PEOPLE TO GO TO IN THE UNITED
STATES?
In general, there is what is known as
the Appropriate Technology Community in the United States. Fred
Schumacher will tell you that there is more going on in Appropriate
Technology in this country than in any country he has ever been.
And by now there are hundreds of these organizations all over
the country. In fact, part of ICA's work fits in with the Appropriate
Technology group. I don't think that you think of yourselves that
way, and I'm not suggesting that you do, but the technology that
you use even in the U.S. would be our version of Appropriate Technology.
ARE THERE ANY EXAMPLES OF SMALL INDUSTRY
COOPERATIVES SIMILAR TO SMALL FARM COPPS ANYWHERE
IN THE WORLD?
Yes, there are quite a lot. There are
more in Scandinavia than anywhere else. The Swedish industrial
cooperatives have been around for a long time and are very
well known. One of the things that is happening in this country
is a search for different patterns of industrial organization
management and ownership, and a lot of people are wondering if
an industrial cooperative might make sense if it would be
more responsive socially than some of the business organizations
we have now. It may well be the cooperatives. Theoretically
the cooperative is that kind of an organization, and I don't
think that there are very many business enterprises in the United
States that are owned on a cooperative basis yet.
RECENTLY THERE WAS A DOCUMENTARY ON CBS
THAT SHOWED THAT THE 'LINCOLN ELECTRIC COMPANY' IN CLEVELAND HAS
A PROFIT SHARING PLAN SO THAT AN AVERAGE WORKER MAKES ABOUT TWENTY
THOUSAND DOLLARS A YEAR.
One movement in the industrial side which
I think is fairly well advanced in the States is the Quality of
Working Life. It is a first step in different systems of ownership
as well as management.
There are a lot of experiments going
on in the country to change the hierarchical nature of the industrial
labor force. The Volvo automobile that comes from Sweden has dispensed
with the assembly line and gone back to a combination of automation
and craft work, because the workers simply refused to work on
the assembly line any more. Under this label of Quality of Working
Life many things are happening which are bringing about a changed
relationship between workers and foremen and are trying to take
monotony out of work.
WHAT IS THIS NEW ORGANIZATION IN WASHINGTON,
"APPROPRIATE TECHNOLOGY INTERNATIONAL", GOING TO BE
DOING?
In the developing countries, there are
quite a few organizations that have a "A.T." label.
Some of them are that and nothing else. More commonly you find
that university groups, research stations, and sometimes business
people simply become interested in Appropriate Technology. At
the university in Ghana, for example, something called a technology
consultancy center was started by a Ghanaian professor with the
help of an Englishman from London. It has now become the biggest
and the best Appropriate Technology organization in Africa. It
is so big that it is beginning to get into the business of industrial
extension. That's a tough area to deal with.
Most of the money that we spend will
go to those organizations to help their staff do research work,
support operations, programs, and pilot programs. A couple of
other things will be involved that are very important. In some
fields we don't have the Appropriate Technology. The problem is
not so much not investigative research but adaptive research.
Can we take a skill that Ts used in Norway, adapt it and put it
in India? There is going to be a great deal of design and field
testing work like this particularly in the fields of alternative
energy and food processing. There is tremendous technology available
in food processing and probably a number of different aspects
of health the kind of health programs that ICA is encouraging.
A third function would be one that would
be a major activity, but not a lot of money, is to strengthen
the linkages in the Appropriate Technology community. There is
something you can refer to in the world today as the A.T. community.
It needs more money and some of our expertise in information systems
so the people in one country can find out who in the world is
working on something and contact them. Strengthening the network
about. he world would be a major function of Appropriate
Technology International.
YOU SAID THIS MORNING YOU THOUGHT INDIA
MIGHT BE RIPE FOR THE KIND OF REPLICATION THAT WE ARE CONTEMPLATING.
WHY DO YOU THINK THAT?
Through the years India has tried every
wrong way that there is to get the villagers involved in development.
By now, nobody is more fed up than the villagers themselves. They
are skeptical that anybody can come in from the government and
say they want to help you. They have just gone through this last
year and a half of the socalled national emergency.
One aspect of that was the sterilization
program that antagonized people. Unexpectedly, they had a chance
to change the government, and they did it. This has given people
a feeling of hope that perhaps they have a chance this time where
they haven't before.
If somebody comes along and says, "I
can show you how to do it", and shows them how they can work
together and do things they have not done in the past, they could
do it. One of the major problems in the country is that government
officials don't know how to talk to villagers. The typical civil
servant, or someone who works in a foreign aid agency cannot go
out and talk to a village. He wouldn't have the slightest idea
what to talk about. But, you people can show government officials
how to talk to villagers. Three fourths of the government officials
are quite willing to work more cooperatively with villages if
they knew how to do it. But they quite honestly don't know how.
So, I think the combination of the circumstance in India and your
proven capacity is sort of a favorable conjunction of events.
RECENTLY THE GOVERNMENT OF THE U.S. HAS
SAID IT IS GOING TO BE INVOLVED IN COMPREHENSIVE SOCIAL, ECONOMIC,
AND ENVIRONMENTAL PLANNING OF ALL KINDS AND THAT THE IMPLEMENTATION
OF THAT WILL BE THROUGH FEDERAL AND STATE PLANNING AGENCIES; TECHNICAL
PLANNING TAKING UP WHAT NEEDS TO BE DONE AND PROVIDING THE MODELS
TO DO IT. HOW DOES THAT STAND IN RELATION TO LOCAL COMMUNITIES
DOING THEIR OWN PLANNING RATHER THAN TURNING TO GOVERNMENT OR
TURNING TO PLANNERS TO DO IT FOR THEM?
I don't think the centralization of administration
has much impact on anything unless it is combined with participation.
What you describe could be helpful only if the Federal government
and State government rejuvenate and invigorate local government.
The future of democracy in this country is mostly a matter of
trying to figure out the forms of urban local government, because
we are an urbanized population and we are going to continue to
be. This is why I attach so much importance to Ivy City in Washington
and Fifth City in Chicago. What they are to me is local government
of the future. That's what they ought to be. I was amused when
I was at Ivy City talking to some of the people there about the
relationships with the D.C. government. It sounded exactly like
what the villagers have told me about the government in their
countries no difference at all.