[Oe List ...] Fwd: Stratfor on economic crisis
Jack Gilles
icabombay at igc.org
Wed Oct 1 12:23:18 EDT 2008
>
Dear Colleagues,
If you can stand another article on the current crisis I think you'll
find the following one quite fair and balanced (with due
acknowledgement to FOX News!). I found it quite helpful to understand
the situation and options before Congress. I won't add any editorial,
just enjoy.
G&P,
Jack
> The Political Nature of the Economic Crisis
>
> Stratfor Today »-- September 30, 2008
>
> By George Friedman
>
> Classical economists like Adam Smith and David Ricardo referred to
> their discipline as “political economy.” Smith’s great work, “The
> Wealth of Nations,” was written by the man who held the chair in
> moral philosophy at the University of Glasgow. This did not seem odd
> at the time and is not odd now. Economics is not a freestanding
> discipline, regardless of how it is regarded today. It is a
> discipline that can only be understood when linked to politics,
> since the wealth of a nation rests on both these foundations, and it
> can best be understood by someone who approaches it from a moral
> standpoint, since economics makes significant assumptions about both
> human nature and proper behavior.
>
> The modern penchan t to regard economics as a discrete science
> parallels the belief that economics is a distinct sphere of
> existence — at its best when it is divorced from political and even
> moral considerations. Our view has always been that the economy can
> only be understood and forecast in the context of politics, and that
> the desire to separate the two derives from a moral teaching that
> Smith would not embrace. Smith understood that the word “economy”
> without the adjective “political” did not describe reality. We need
> to bear Smith in mind when we try to understand the current crisis.
> Societies have two sorts of financial crises. The first sort is so
> large it overwhelms a society’s ability to overcome it, and the
> society sinks deeper into dysfunction and poverty. In the second
> sort, the society has the resources to manage the situation — albeit
> at a collective price. Societies that can manage the crisis have two
> broad strategies. The first strategy is to allow the market to solve
> the problem over time. The second strategy is to have the state
> organize the resources of society to speed up the resolution. The
> market solution is more efficient over time, producing better
> outcomes and disciplining financial decision-making in the long run.
> But the market solution can create massive collateral damage, such
> as high unemployment, on the way to the superior resolution. The
> state-organized resolution creates inequities by not sufficiently
> punishing poor economic decisions, and creates long-term
> inefficiencies that are costly. But it has the virtue of being
> quicker and mitigating collateral damage.
> Three Views of the Financial Crisis
>
> There is a first group that argues the current financial crisis
> already has outstripped available social resources, so that there is
> no market or state solution. This group asserts that the imbalances
> created in the financial markets are so vast that the market
> solution must consist of an extended period of depression. Any
> attempt by the state to appropriate social resources to solve the
> financial imbalance not only will be ineffective, it will prolong
> the crisis even further, although perhaps buying some minor
> alleviation up front. The thinking goes that the financial crisis
> has been building for years and the economy can no longer be
> protected from it, and that therefore an extended period of
> discipline and austerity — beginning with severe economic
> dislocations — is inevitable. This is not a majority view, but it is
> widespread; it opposes government action on the grounds that the
> government will make a terrible situation worse.
>
> A second group argues that the financial crisis has not outstripped
> the ability of society — organized by the state — to manage, but
> that it has outstripped the market’s ability to manage it. The
> financial markets have been the problem, according to this view, and
> have created a massive liquidity crisis. The economy — as distinct
> from the financial markets — is relatively sound, but if the
> liquidity crisis is left unsolved, it will begin to affect the
> economy as a whole. Since the financial markets are unable to solve
> the problem in a time frame that will not dramatically affect the
> economy, the state must mobilize resources to impose a solution on
> the financial markets, introducing liquidity as the preface to any
> further solutions. This group believes, like the first group, that
> the financial crisis could have profound economic ramifications. But
> the second group also believes it is possible to contain the
> consequences. This is the view of the Bush administration, the
> congressional leadership, the Federal Reserve Board and most
> economic leaders.
>
> There is a third group that argues that the state mobilization of
> resources to save the financial system is in fact an attempt to save
> financial institutions, including many of those whose imprudence and
> avarice caused the current crisis. This group divides in two. The
> first subgroup agrees the current financial crisis could have
> profound economic consequences, but believes a solution exists that
> wou ld bring liquidity to the financial markets without rescuing the
> culpable. The second subgroup argues that the threat to the economic
> system is overblown, and that the financial crisis will correct
> itself without major state intervention but with some limited
> implementation of new regulations.
>
> The first group thus views the situation as beyond salvation, and
> certainly rejects any political solution as incapable of addressing
> the issues from the standpoint of magnitude or competence. This
> group is out of the political game by its own rules, since for it
> the situation is beyond the ability of politics to make a difference
> — except perhaps to make the situation worse.
>
> The second group represents the establishment consensus, which is
> that the markets cannot solve the problem but the federal government
> can — provided it acts quickly and decisively enough.
> The third group spoke Sept. 29, when a coalition of Democrats and
> Republicans defeated the establishment proposal. For a myriad of
> reasons, some contradictory, this group opposed the bailout. The
> reasons ranged from moral outrage at protecting the interests of the
> perpetrators of this crisis to distrust of a plan implemented by
> this presidential administration, from distrust of the amount of
> power ceded the Treasury Department of any administration to a
> feeling the problem could be managed. It was a diverse group that
> focused on one premise — namely, that delay would not lead to
> economic catastrophe.
> From Economic to Political Problem
>
> The problem ceased to be an economic problem months ago. More
> precisely, the economic problem has transformed into a political
> problem. Ever since the collapse of Bear Stearns, the primary actor
> in the drama has been the federal government and the Federal
> Reserve, with its powers increasing as the nature of potential
> market outcomes became more and more unsettling. At a certain point,
> the size of the problem outstripped the legislated resources of the
> Treasury and the Fed, so they went to Congress for more power and
> money. This time, they were blocked.
>
> It is useful to reflect on the nature of the crisis. It is a tale
> that can be as complicated as you wish to make it, but it is in
> essence simple and elegant. As interest rates declined in recent
> years, investors — particularly conservative ones — sought to
> increase their return without giving up safety and liquidity. They
> wanted something for nothing, and the market obliged. They were
> given instruments ultimately based on mortgages on private homes.
> They therefore had a very real asset base — a house — and therefore
> had collateral. The value of homes historically had risen, and
> therefore the value of the assets appeared secured. Financial
> instruments of increasing complexity eventually were devised, which
> were bought by conservative investors. In due course, these
> instruments were bought by less conservative investors, who used
> them as collateral for borrowing money. They used this money to buy
> other instruments in a pyramiding scheme that rested on one premise:
> the existence of houses whose value remained stable or grew.
>
> Unfortunately, housing prices declined. A period of uncertainty
> about the value of the paper based on home mortgages followed.
> People claimed to be confused as to what the real value of the paper
> was. In fact, they were not so much confused as deceptive. They
> didn’t want to reveal that the value of the paper had declined
> dramatically. At a certain point, the facts could no longer be
> hidden, and vast amounts of value evaporated — taking with them not
> only the vast pyramids of those who first created the instruments
> and then borrowed heavily against them, but also the more
> conservative investors trying to put their money in a secure space
> while squeezing out a few extra points of interest. The decline in
> housing prices triggered massive losses of money in the financial
> markets, as well as reluctance to lend based on uncertainty of
> values. The result was a liquidity crisis, which simply meant that a
> lot of people had gone broke and that those who still had money
> weren’t lending it — certainly not to financial institutions.
> The S&L Precedent
>
> Such financial meltdowns based on shifts in real estate prices are
> not new. In the 1970s, regulations on savings and loans (S&Ls) had
> changed. Previously, S&Ls had been limited to lending in the
> consumer market, primarily in mortgages for homes. But the
> regulations shifted, and they became allowed to invest more broadly.
> The assets of these small banks, of which there were thousands, were
> attractive in that they were a pool of cash available for
> investment. The S&Ls subsequently went into commercial real estate,
> sometimes with their old management, sometimes with new management
> who had bought them, as their depositors no longer held them.
>
> The infusion of money from the S&Ls drove up the price of commercial
> real estate, which the institutions regarded as stable and
> conservative investments, not unlike private homes. They did not
> take into account that their presence in the market was driving up
> the price of commercial real estate irrationally, however, or that
> commercial real estate prices fluctuate dramatically. As commercial
> real estate values started to fall, the assets of the S&Ls
> contracted until most failed. An entire sector of the financial
> system simply imploded, crushing shareholders and threatening a
> massive liquidity crisis. By the late 1980s, the entire sector had
> melted down, and in 1989 the federal government intervened.
>
> The federal government intervened in that crisis as it had in
> several crises large and small since 1929. Using the resources at
> its disposal, the federal government took over failed S&Ls and their
> real estate investments, creating the Resolution Trust Corp. (RTC).
> The amount of assets acquired was about $394 billion dollars in 1989
> — or 6.7 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) — making it larger
> than the $700 billion dollars — or 5 percent of GDP — being
> discussed now. Rather than flooding the markets with foreclosed
> commercial property, creating havoc in the market and further
> destroying assets, the RTC held the commercial properties off the
> market, maintaining their price artificially. They then sold off the
> foreclosed properties in a multiyear sequence that recovered much of
> what had been spent acquiring the properties. More important, it
> prevented the decline in commercial real estate from accelerating
> and creating liquidity crises throughout the entire economy.
>
> Many of those involved in S&Ls were ruined. Others managed to use
> the RTC system to recover real estate and to profit. Still others
> came in from the outside and used the RTC system to build fortunes.
> The RTC is not somethin g to use as moral lesson for your children.
> But the RTC managed to prevent the transformation of a financial
> crisis into an economic meltdown. It disrupted market operations by
> introducing large amounts of federal money to bring liquidity to the
> system, then used the ability of the federal government — not shared
> by individuals — to hold on to properties. The disruption of the
> market’s normal operations was designed to avoid a market outcome.
> By holding on to the assets, the federal government was able to
> create an artificial market in real estate, one in which supply was
> constrained by the government to manage the value of commercial real
> estate. It did not work perfectly — far from it. But it managed to
> avoid the most feared outcome, which was a depression.
>
> There have been many other federal interventions in the markets,
> such as the bailout of Chrysler in the 1970s or the intervention
> into failed Third World bonds in the 1980s. Political interventions
> in the American (or global) marketplace are hardly novel. They are
> used to control the consequences of bad decisions in the
> marketplace. Though they introduce inefficiencies and frequently
> reward foolish decisions, they achieve a single end: limiting the
> economic consequences of these decisions on the economy as a whole.
> Good idea or not, these interventions are institutionalized in
> American economic life and culture. The ability of Americans to be
> shocked at the thought of bailouts is interesting, since they are
> not all that rare, as judged historically.
>
> The RTC showed the ability of federal resources — using taxpayer
> dollars — to control financial processes. In the end, the S&L story
> was simply one of bad decisions resulting in a shortage of dollars.
> On top of a vast economy, the U.S. government can mobilize large
> amounts of dollars as needed. It therefore can redefine the market
> for money. It did so in 1989 during the S&L crisis, and there was a
> general acceptance it would do so again Sept. 29.
> The RTC Model and the Road Ahead
>
> As discussed above, the first group argues the current crisis is so
> large that it is beyond the federal government’s ability to
> redefine. More precisely, it would argue that the attempt at
> intervention would unleash other consequences — such as weakening
> dollars and inflation — meaning the cure would be worse than the
> disease. That may be the case this time, but it is difficult to see
> why the consequences of this bailout would be profoundly different
> from the RTC bailout — namely, a normal recession that would
> probably happe n anyway.
>
> The debate between the political leadership and those opposing its
> plan is more interesting. The fundamental difference between the RTC
> and the current bailout was institutional. Congress created a semi-
> independent agency operating under guidelines to administer the S&L
> bailout. The proposal that was defeated Sept. 29 would have given
> the secretary of the Treasury extraordinary personal powers to
> dispense the money. Some also argued that the return on the federal
> investment was unclear, whereas in the RTC case it was fairly clear.
> In the end, all of this turned on the question of urgency. The
> establishment group argued that time was running out and the
> financial crisis was about to morph into an economic crisis. Those
> voting against the proposal argued there was enough time to have a
> more defined solution.
>
> There was obviously a more direct political dimension to all this.
> Elections are just more than a month a way, and the seat of every
> U.S. representative is in contest. The public is deeply distrustful
> of the establishment, and particularly of the idea that the people
> who caused the crisis might benefit from the bailout. The
> congressional opponents of the plan needed to demonstrate
> sensitivity to public opinion. Having done so, if they force a
> redefinition of the bailout plan, an additional 13 votes can likely
> be found to pass the measure.
>
> But the key issue is this: Are the resources of the United States
> sufficient to redef ine financial markets in such a way as to manage
> the outcome of this crisis, or has the crisis become so large that
> even the resources of a $14 trillion economy mobilized by the state
> can’t do the job? If the latter is true, then all other discussions
> are irrelevant. Events will take their course, and nothing can be
> done. But if that is not true, that means that politics defines the
> crisis, as it has other crisis. In that case, the federal government
> can marshal the resources needed to redefine the markets and the key
> decision-makers are not on Wall Street, but in Washington. Thus,
> when the chips are down, the state trumps the markets.
>
> All of this may not be desirable, efficient or wise, but as an
> empirical fact, it is the way American society works and has worked
> for a long time. We are seeing a case study in it — including the
> possibility the state will refuse to act, creating an interesting
> and profound situation. This would allow the market alone to define
> the outcome of the crisis. This has not been allowed in extreme
> crises in 75 years, and we suspect this tradition of intervention
> will not be broken now. The federal government will act in due
> course, and an institutional resolution taking power from the
> Treasury and placing it in the equivalent of the RTC will emerge.
> The question is how much time remains before mass ive damage is done
> to the economy.
>
> Find phone numbers fast with the New AOL Yellow Pages!
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://wedgeblade.net/pipermail/oe_wedgeblade.net/attachments/20081001/fdb0fb02/attachment-0001.html>
More information about the OE
mailing list